Hilary Term Lecture 1.

Abuse of Dominance Continued

Return to Main Menu



Limit Pricing I.

Limit Pricing II


Monopoly Pricing.

In Lucazeau v Sacem the ECJ concluded that:

'When an undertaking holding a dominant position imposes scales of fees for its services which are appreciably higher than those charged in other member states, and where a comparison of the fee levels has been made on a consistent basis, this difference must be regarded as indicative of an abuse of a dominant position. In such a case it is for the undertaking in question to justify the difference by reference to objective dissimilarities between the situation in the member state concerned and the situation prevailing in all the other member states.' [1989] ECR 2811.

Court judgement in Sacem disturbing:

Office of Fair Trading - prices can be considered excessive if they allow undertakings to sustain greater profits than would otherwise occur in a competitive market, i.e. 'super-normal profit'.

Prices would not be considered abusive if they occur for short periods within competitive markets, if they reflect superior efficiency, or if they occur in markets where there is innovation to improve products and/or processes.

OFT Guideline 402.

Monopoly pricing not offensive under US law.

Regulation sometimes used to control monopoly pricing


Price Discrimination

Sale of different units of a good or service at different prices where the differential is not equivalent to differences in the cost of supply.

Three conditions necessary for price discrimination:

  1. The firm must have some degree of market power giving it some control over price.
  2. It must be able to segregate its customers into groups with differing price elasticities of demand, i.e. there must be different markets.
  3. There must be no scope for arbitrage, i.e. customers paying the lower price must not be able to sell to those being charged the higher price.

Three Types of Price Discrimination

  1. First Degree
    • Involves charging each individual customer the maximum price which they would be prepared to pay.
    • Normally difficult to engage in first degree price discrimination because it is difficult to prevent arbitrage.
    • MMC found that British Gas engaged in first degree price discrimination.
    • In the case of scarce goods, sealed bid auctions represent a means of engaging in first degree price discrimination.
  2. Second Degree
    • Involves volume discounts.
    • Soft drinks. Six packs may be sold at a lower unit price than individual cans. Simple rationale.
    • Some consumers only want an individual can and will pay higher price. Others might be prepared to buy more than one can if unit price is lower or might buy none at all at the high price charged for an individual can. Such consumers might purchase six packs at lower unit price.
    • Firm gains by charging a high price to those consumers wishing to purchase individual cans, while simultaneously charging a lower unit price to those consumers who are prepared to purchase more than one can, but only at the lower price.
    • Two tier tariffs represent another form of second degree price discrimination. Common in utilities where consumers pay a fixed charge for access plus a separate charge for each unit of the product consumed.
    • Second degree price discrimination commonly observed in many consumer goods markets.
    • Often occurs in oligopolistic markets rather than in those with dominant firm.
  3. Third Degree

Price discrimination frequently welfare enhancing.


Types of behaviour listed as abusive under Section 5 and Article 82 includes:


Case Law on Discrimination


Return to Main Menu